Thursday, July 9, 2015

Book Review: The Monied Metropolis, by Beckert




                This is yet another book review on my adventure in reading over the summer.  Hope you enjoy it, because I certainly enjoyed reading it (the book that is).
There can sometimes be a lot of debate about whether or not capitalism should be, or is, directly associated with the state.  You hear it all the time in the mainstream media/culture:  “Capitalism would be better off without government interference.”[i]  Or, conversely, perhaps you know someone who argues that capitalism is intrinsically linked to government.  Some might even go far enough to suggest that the government is subordinate to those in control of capitalism, suggesting that the republic itself is a façade.  A lot of this becomes conjectured debate, where one side polemically decides that it is sticking to its guns and not budging on the issue.  With respect to the goals and aspirations of bourgeois elitists in the late 19th century, however, it seems quite clear how government and the interests of capital learned to play nice.
                Most narratives of labor and capital in the 19th century focus their attention on the working-class side; its culture, its politics, and its activism.  Historians showed how proletarianization—the conscious development of a sense of class among working class Americans—shifted against the interests of landowning elites after 1850.  In his 2001 text on the development of class in the late 19th century, Sven Beckert focused his attention, instead, on the elites.  But it wasn’t just any elites—which he makes clear in his preface: “The term bourgeoisie grasps more precisely the historical formation with which I am concerned.  ‘Elite,’ for example, does not sufficiently distinguish the bourgeoisie as a fundamentally different kind of elite from other elites who have come before or after.”[ii]  His text, The Monied Metropolis, examines the formation of the contemporary, post-Civil War bourgeoisie in New York City—the famed “new capital of the world.”[iii]  New York City was a fitting icon for the narrative, since much of the post-Reconstruction boom is associated with the city’s immense commercial and industrial growth until superseded by Chicago and Los Angeles in the 1920s.  Beckert’s book provides us a unique view, however, into the complicated world of industrial and merchant wealth in the late 19th century to show that government involvement with capital interests was certainly a matter of fact.

                Merchant and industrial capitalists saw a major turn in the 1850s away from conditions that allowed them to succeed in a politically fragmented manner.  Previous agreements between slave-owning elites in the South reached conflicts as Abolitionism swept the Northern states.  Karl Marx once famously argued in a series of articles posted for the Viennese paper Die Presse that the Civil War was the inevitable outcome of two opposing class interests (industrial/merchant capitalists in North, slaveowners in South) both seeking expansion of their productive systems.[iv]  The previous conflicts between industrial and merchant businessmen—primarily over political party preferences and economic competition—quickly dissipated in the wake of tension with the South.  Beckert describes how both industrial and merchant bourgeois elites, “which had been so sharply divided in the 1850s and earlier, had merged into a common agenda, one centered on the matrix of domestic industrial development.”[v]  Whereas previous generations of business and upper-middle class elitists built separate and isolated cultural and social institutions, the bourgeoisie of New York City build common ones that they “defined as part of a conscious effort at stabilizing their own class.”[vi]
                In order to frame their culture and impose social institutions to reflect said culture, the late 19th century bourgeoisie had the vestige of the State to rely on.  Whatever people want to claim about the history of laisse-faire capitalism in the United States, “capital accumulation was still in numerous ways based on the power of local, state, and national governments: court enforced contracts; Congress determined tariffs; the federal government registered patents; state legislatures passed incorporation laws, build canals, and gave railroad grants; state militias forced Indians out of western territories; and local police enforced the social order.”  Because of this fundamental reality of late-19th century American life, many of those in the industrial and merchant businesses—including bankers, builders, and renters—felt “compelled to involve themselves in politics.”[vii]  As well, most revenue generated by the state in the form of taxation and customs duties “paid for more of the operations of the federal government.”  The actions of the federal government that could be considered breaching of states’ rights and personal liberties, such as territorial expansion and re-districting, “depended ultimately on resources mobilized by economic elites.”[viii]
                The issues of the North with the South, however, were not the only factors in facilitating the class consciousness of New York City’s (and thus industrial and merchant America’s) bourgeoisie by 1897.  The rise of proletarianization and trade unionism had a particularly powerful impact.  Previously, industrial and merchant businessmen were tolerate of unions to the extent that they created a sense of agency among workers and allowed for production to continue.  However, “a pattern of downturns shook the economy violently in frequent intervals during the 1870s, 1880s, and 1890s.”  Persistent workplace struggles and an increasingly vibrant labor movement directed attention toward the political sphere.  Many working Americans and even small businesses felt that “the spreading dependence on wage work…threatened the very foundations of a republic of small producers.”[ix]  By the 1880s, “the economic and political power of bourgeois Americans remained illegitimate in the eyes of many citizens.”[x]  Further consolidation of political power, clearly, was not in the best interests of the economic elite.
            Previously, political power laid in the hands of landownership and its appropriation, along with the enterprises of the nation’s oldest banks.  Documented from a multitude of schools including political economy, Marxism, the Annals School, and philosophy in general, the shift in the 1850s coincided with the aspiring political ascendancy of the labor movement.  Merchant and industrial leaders were keenly aware of the profound resistance to political power when it became antithetical to the needs and pressures of the broad citizen base.  Beckert shows how, in a unsuspecting fashion, the New York City bourgeois elite found ways to pander down middle-paths which “historians have called ‘progressivism.”  The result was a relationship between society and the state that was “significantly reshaped,” and fostered the booming development of “a new foreign policy” directed at finding “new ways of legitimizing a corporate economic order.”  The bourgeoisie, in other words, were conscious of the risks they took when engaging with politics, and acting accordingly to both shroud their involvement while remaining directly involved in political affairs.
                In their attempt to legitimize their role in American society while avoiding direct attention—since part of Beckert’s thesis is that the bourgeoisie never desired to be portrayed as a uniform or unified class—the industrial and merchant bourgeoisie of New York formed new “preferences rooted in an awareness of the systemic nature of the crisis.”  It was this specific reorientation—this new cultural and social identity—that Beckert claims “reshap[ed] modern America.”[xi]  The overall goal was to reinforce the notion of 'supply and demand' as 'natural functions' of a society, similar to scientific laws that dictated the physical realm.  Everything from wages to job availability was considered to be the almighty result of entrenched economic laws; and consideration for how these laws were both facilitated and encouraged in society were ignored.  And indeed, it worked.  The bourgeoisie emerged more politically and economically intelligent, and by 1890 saw its first major success with the Sherman Antitrust Act and the 1889 New Jersey Incorporation law.  Both laws, pushed and financially backed by New York’s bourgeoisie, “established and legitimized the corporation as a form of business organization that would internalize markets and diminish competition, thus adding to economic stability.”  By the time the Federal Reserve came around, the city’s economic elite established “greater federal regulation of the banking industry.”[xii]
                Beckert’s book begs us to question why we even bother wondering about laisse-faire capitalism—as though the history of the world’s most successful economic elite doesn’t spell it out for us?  In Beckert’s own words, “behind the camouflage of familiarity lurks the history of a social class that can be identified an observed in action, a class that had developed a distinctive sense of itself by the end of the nineteenth century, and that was able to mobilize on that basis.”  It was specifically the actions of the late 19th century bourgeoisie—“their access to capital, their ability to forge dense social networks, their influence on the state, their capacity to formulate ideas explaining the world to themselves and others have stamped the lives of all Americans”—that defined them as a class.  We can’t pretend that these individuals believed in the success of business on the platform of idealistic free-market capitalism—they purposefully engaged with the state and society at large with an over-arching goal of curbing social development into their favor.  This is a powerful thing to consider when discussion contemporary and historical political economy; thankfully Beckert’s analysis sets a high-bar standard.



[ii] Beckert, Sven.  The Monied Metropolis (Harvard University Press, 2001), 6
[iii] Ibid, 78
[iv] Karl Marx.  "The North American Civil War," Die Presse (October 25, 1861)  www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1861/10/25.htm (accessed September 27, 2013)
[v] Beckert, 323
[vi] Ibid
[vii] Ibid, 79
[viii] Ibid
[ix] Ibid, 324
[x] Ibid, 325
[xi] Ibid
[xii] Ibid, 327

No comments:

Post a Comment